We don't owe it to ourselves

By Don Boudreaux.

Writing in the Jan. 2 New York Times, Paul Krugman noted that "U.S. debt is, to a large extent, money we owe to ourselves."
Krugman goes on: Unlike a family saddled with debt -- which is owed to people outside of the family -- a government indebted mainly to its own citizens doesn't really have a debt burden. Except for some minor secondary effects (which can be safely ignored), the wealth of the nation isn't reduced when such public debt is repaid. The creditor (citizens) is one with the debtor (citizens). Because Americans receive most of the money that Americans pay to retire debt, Americans as a group aren't made poorer by repaying the debt.
And so, sighs Krugman with relief, public debt is nothing much to worry about because we owe it to ourselves.
Clever argument, that. Too bad it's wrong.
If it were true, unlimited wealth would be possible for everyone. A government pressed to build more hospitals or to subsidize more corn farming could simply pay for these programs with borrowed funds. If paying off any debts incurred to make such programs possible inflicts virtually no cost on the country, every government program financed with money borrowed from its citizens is free. Costless. Without sacrifice.
In such a world, there'd be no reason for government to refrain from supplying any good or service that citizens want: not only national defense, police protection, efficient courts and world-class schooling, but even extravagances that are usually prohibitively costly when individuals buy them privately -- extravagances such as Tahitian vacations, Lamborghinis and retirement at the age of 30.
If the trick to making the supply of goods and services costless is merely to have the state finance their provision with debt, then humankind has been foolishly missing out on untold riches for ages. Using government debt, we can have Dom Perignon and private jets for everyone!
Obviously, every 12-year-old understands that goods and services are not made free merely by financing their provision with funds borrowed from Smith, who is a citizen of the same country as Jones, who is a taxpayer who will be held responsible for repaying the loan. And yet, a Nobel-laureate economist publicly endorses a proposition that differs in no fundamental respect from the one that every 12-year-old correctly understands to be false.
What's going on here?
Until the 1930s, the classical economic understanding was that the burden of government debt is passed on to future generations and that the need to pay off this debt was a genuine burden to the economy as a whole. But in the 1930s, along came John Maynard Keynes' "revolution" in economic thought. And Keynesians' "revolutionary" mode of economic thinking (which is largely a gussied-up rehash of economic fallacies that were popular prior to the writings of Adam Smith) led economists, step by unsuspecting step, to reach mistaken conclusions.
Keynesian economics' single biggest flaw on this front is its practice of lumping all people in a country into a single category and focusing exclusively on how much "it" -- this collective -- spends in the aggregate. If Jones' taxes rise by $100 and if Smith receives this $100, then as long as we can assume that Smith's "propensity" to spend is the same as that of Jones, any such tax-and-transfer scheme presents no problem to the economy.
Such a conclusion is silly. In my next column I will explore the "we owe it to ourselves" fallacy in greater detail.

Does the U.S. Economy Need More Boeings or More Facebooks?

By Daniel Ikenson.

Remember the story of that once-great nation that sacrificed its well-paying manufacturing jobs for low-wage, burger-flipping jobs at the altar of free trade? At one time, that story was a popular rejoinder of manufacturing unions and their apologists to the inconvenient facts that, despite manufacturing employment attrition, the economy was producing an average of 1.84 million net new jobs per year every year between 1983 and 2007, a quarter century during which the real value of U.S. trade increased five-fold and real GDP more than doubled.
The claim that service-sector jobs are uniformly inferior to manufacturing jobs lost credibility, as average wages in the two broad sectors converged in 2005 and have been consistently higher in services ever since. In 2011, the average service sector wage stood at $19.18 per hour, as compared to $18.94 in manufacturing. (But I don’t recall buying any $25-$30 hamburgers last year.)
One reason for U.S. manufacturing wages being higher than services wages in the past is that manufacturing labor unions “succeeded” at winning concessions from management that turned out to be unsustainable. The value of manufacturing labor didn’t justify its exorbitant costs, which encouraged producers to substitute other inputs for labor and to adopt more efficient techniques and technologies.
With the superiority-of-manufacturing-wages argument discredited, new arguments have emerged attempting to make the case that there is something special – even sacred – about the manufacturing sector that should afford it special policy consideration. Many of those arguments, however, conflate the meanings of manufacturing sector employment and manufacturing sector health or they rely on statistics that don’t support their arguments or they become irrelevant by losing sight of the fact that resources are scarce and must be used efficiently. And too often the prescriptions offered would place the economy on the slippery slope that descends into industrial policy.
I recently submitted this rebuttal to this essay by an environmental sciences professor by the name of Vaclav Smil, who commits those errors. (Judging from the tone of his mostly evasiveresponse to my rebuttal, Smil doesn’t seem to have much tolerance for views that differ from his own.) Perhaps most noteworthy among Smil’s slew of questionable arguments is his claim that manufacturing companies, like Boeing, valued at $50 billion, are better for the economy than service companies like Facebook, which is also valued at $50 billion because
[i]n terms of job creation there is no comparison… Boeing employs some 160,000 people, whereas Facebook only employs 2,000.
Granted, Boeing’s operations support more jobs. But is that better for the economy than a company that provides the same value using 1/80th the amount of labor resources? Of course not. We need economic growth in the United States to create wealth and increase living standards. Economic growth and employment are not one and the same thing. In fact, the essence of growth is creating more value with fewer inputs (or at lower input cost). Creating jobs is easy. Instead of bulldozers, mandate shovels; instead of shovels, require spoons. Inefficient production techniques can create more jobs than efficient ones, but they don’t create value, which is the economic goal.
With 2,000 workers producing the same value as 160,000 – one producing the same value as 80 – Facebook is 80 times more productive than Boeing, freeing up 158,000 workers for other more productive endeavors (perhaps 79 more Facebook-type operations). If those companies were individual countries, the per capita GDP in Facebookland would be $25 million, but only $3.125 million in Boeingia. Where would you rather live?
Smil calls my assessment a cruel joke, presumably for its failure to empathize with unemployed and underemployed Americans, by considering value before job creation.  But policies designed to encourage more Boeing’s, as Smil supports (or, in fairness, any businesses that employ at least X number of people or meet this requirement or that) would likely retard the establishment of firms, like Facebook, that produce the goods and services that people want to consume. The provision of goods and services that people want to buy – rather than those that policymakers in Washington think people want to buy (or are happy to force them to buy) – is the essence of value creation.
Thus, policies should incentivize (or, at least not discourage) the kind of innovation and entrepreneurship needed to create more Facebooks? This kind of business formation occurs in environments where the rule of law is clear and abided; where there is greater certainty to the business and political climate; where the specter of asset expropriation is negligible; where physical and administrative infrastructure is in good shape; where the local work force is productive; where skilled foreigners aren’t chased back to their own shores; where there are limited physical, political, and administrative frictions; and so on. In other words, restraining the role of government to its proper functions and nothing more would create the environment most likely to produce more Facebooks in both the manufacturing and services sectors.

Copiar o no copiar, that is…

Por Arcadi Espada.


Mientras Nicholas Carr sigue recorriendo el mundo con su estupidez a cuestas (¿Por qué google nos está volviendo estúpidos?), el biólogo Mark Pagel se preguntaba en un aula reciente de Edge si internet va a volvernos exponencialmente más inteligentes y más creativos. Lo duda. La razón fundamental, y jibarizada, es que los cinco individuos innovadores que bajaron a la tribu humana del árbol se bastan y se sobran (¡en número!) para guiar a la tribu internáutica, cumpliendo así el mandato de la selección natural que ante la innovación, cara y costosa, privilegia la copia. Así, las masas instaladas en las redes sociales cumplen con una perfección monstruosa el papel de replicadores de ideas que caracteriza el mecanismo genético. Dice Pagel: «Una o dos personas en la banda son suficientes para que los demás copiemos. No hace falta que todos seamos innovadores. Podemos copiar las mejores innovaciones y beneficiarnos todos de ellas.» O sea: es la replicación lo que de verdad constituye el valor añadido de la red. ¡Y de ese país llamado China! Cabría pensar que el contagio internáutico promociona el nacimiento de nuevas ideas. Pero, al decir de Pagel, sólo promociona su viaje. Ante una lanza nueva la inmensa mayoría de individuos no se plantea cómo mejorarla, sino cómo copiarla. Y la cuestión es que la gente tiene hoy muchas cosas interesantes que copiar. Entre las correcciones de la utopía internáutica esta es la más profunda y mesurada que he leído. De ahí que me limite a replicarla.

El déficit del PSOE: Donde dije 6... digo 8


Educación. Andrés Oppenheimer


El desafío digital por Andrés Oppenheimer.

¿Menos pobres y menos educados?Por Andrés Oppenheimer.

Mentes brillantes, pero desperdiciadas. Andrés Oppenheimer

Víctimas, 13 de enero: Francisco Gómez Gómez-Jiménez, Miguel García Poyo y Rafael Leiva Loro

Libertad Digital.


A las tres de la mañana del sábado 13 de enero de 1979, ETA asesinaba mediante la explosión de dos bombas en la localidad guipuzcoana de Azpeitia, a los guardias civiles FRANCISCO GÓMEZ GÓMEZ-JIMÉNEZ MIGUEL GARCÍA POYO. Un compañero de ambos, Francisco Mota Calvo, falleció dos días después.
Los hechos ocurrieron de la siguiente forma. Al paso de dos Land Rover de la Guardia Civil por la carretera que une el santuario de Loyola y la población de Azpeitia, el etarra José María Zaldúa Corta accionó a distancia un potente artefacto por medio de un sistema eléctrico conectado a unas pilas y 150 metros de cable que se extendían por el monte. El artefacto estaba adosado al talud derecho de la carretera, y la explosión destrozó la parte delantera del segundo de los dos vehículos, lanzándolo fuera de la calzada a una distancia aproximada de quince metros.
A consecuencia de la deflagración, en la que los terroristas utilizaron entre cinco y diez kilos de goma-2 y abundante tornillería que actuó como metralla, perdió la vida en el acto el guardia civil Francisco Gómez Gómez-Jiménez, que llevaba tres años en el Cuerpo, y quedó gravemente herido su compañero, también guardia civil, Juan Muñiz Sánchez, de 28 años y natural de Baeza (Jaén). Fue ingresado en la Residencia Sanitaria Nuestra Señora de Aránzazu de San Sebastián y tardaría casi quince meses en curarse.
Cuatro horas después, en torno a las siete de la mañana de ese mismo día, un grupo de guardias civiles, entre los que se encontraban miembros del Equipo de Desactivación de Explosivos de la Comandancia de la Guardia Civil de Guipúzcoa, procedía a analizar el mecanismo del artefacto utilizado en el atentado.
Durante la inspección observaron un paquete sospechoso, que al parecer estaba conectado aldetonante de la primera carga. Al manipularlo hizo explosión, provocando una nueva víctima mortal, el agente de la Benemérita Miguel García Poyo, e hiriendo gravemente al guardia civil, Técnico Especialista en Desactivación de Artefactos Explosivos (TEDAX) Francisco Mota Calvo. Este agente fallecería dos días después al no poder superar la gravedad de las heridas.
La proximidad de ambas cargas hizo pensar inicialmente que pudiese tratarse de una trampa, pero lo más probable es que se trató de un fallo en el mecanismo de activación por lo que, en un principio, ambos artefactos hubieran tenido que explotar al mismo tiempo.
Francisco Gómez Gómez-Jiménez, natural de Almería, tenía 29 años, estaba casado y dejaba huérfanos a dos hijos.
Miguel García Poyo, natural de la localidad de San Martín de Pedroso (Zamora), de 29 años de edad, estaba también casado y era padre de tres hijos.

[...]



Dieciséis años después, el 13 de enero de 1995, dos terroristas de ETA entraron en torno a las 13:00 horas en las oficinas de expedición de pasaportes y DNI situadas en pleno centro de Bilbao y dispararon repetidamente contra los policías nacionales RAFAEL LEIVA LORO y Domingo Durán Díez.
Rafael Leiva Loro recibió varios disparos en la cabeza que le ocasionaron la muerte inmediata. Su compañero Domingo Durán sobrevivió, aunque recibió un disparo en las cervicales que le dejó tetrapléjico y postrado en una cama durante ocho largos años, hasta su fallecimiento el 7 de marzo de 2003.
La reacción de los agentes de las oficinas propició la inmediata detención de uno de los presuntos asesinos, Jorge González Endemaño, de 22 años, supuesto miembro legal de ETA. Este sería condenado en 1998 junto a Agustín Almaraz Larrañaga, José Ignacio Alonso Rubio y Aitor Fresnedo Guerricabeitia, por un delito de asesinato y otro en grado de tentativa, puesto que Domingo Durán murió varios años después, en marzo de 2003. Posteriormente, en marzo de 2002 fue extraditado por Francia el etarra Asier Ormazabal Lizeaga, que en 2004 fue también condenado por el atentado contra Rafael Leiva y Domingo Durán a 30 y 20 años respectivamente.
Rafael Leiva Loro tenía 43 años, era natural de Atarfe (Granada), estaba separado y era padre deseis hijos. Ingresó en la Policía en 1977 y llevaba diez años destinado en el País Vasco.

La función empresarial. Elementos de la Acción Humana.

Por Jesús Huerta de Soto.

La Función Empresarial. Definición. Elementos de la Acción Humana: fin, valor, medio, utilidad, escasez.


Aquí el resto de los vídeos.